StudentShare
Contact Us
Sign In / Sign Up for FREE
Search
Go to advanced search...
Free

Mergers and Acquisitions in the UK Banking - Term Paper Example

Cite this document
Summary
The author of this paper "Mergers and Acquisitions in the UK Banking" focuses and presents mergers and acquisitions among UK banks and is a study of the general trend for mergers and acquisitions and their impact on businesses and the financial sector in general…
Download full paper File format: .doc, available for editing
GRAB THE BEST PAPER98.3% of users find it useful

Extract of sample "Mergers and Acquisitions in the UK Banking"

Mergers and Acquisitions in UK Banking Abstract: This paper focuses on mergers and acquisitions among UK banks and is a study of the general trend for M&A and their impact on businesses and the financial sector in general. The hypothesis is that the increase in mergers and acquisitions among banks in the UK is a trend which occurs due to banking dynamics and the purpose of this study is to discuss these dynamics. Merging banks have the opportunity to consolidate services and initiate new businesses. The efficiency of the M&A will be the measure of the market power of the consolidated institution compared to the position the separate entities held before the merger. I seek to identify the positive and negative trends of such M&A, as well as the reason for the This includes the static effects of the assimilation of business practices of both parent institutions as well as the dynamic effects of the refocused business. I address the issue of the measure of market power of a financial institutions and whether regulators rely on accurate and effective procedures to evaluate the competitive effects of a merger. Introduction Within the last quarter of the 20th century, the number of commercial banks in the UK has decreased by about 35 percent while around the same period there has been an average of more than four hundred mergers per year. These two trends raise important concerns on the effect of M&A. It may be assumed that banks are merging to fully exploit business potential of a larger scale and scope. The possible improvements in efficiency may translate into welfare gains for the economy, to the extent that customers pay lower prices for banks' services or are able to obtain higher quality services or services that could not have been offered before. However, looking from the public policy viewpoint of M&A, it is equally important to focus on the effect of this restructuring process on the competitive capabilities of the banking industry. If banks gain market power from merging, they will be able to charge higher than usual prices for their products, thus inflicting welfare costs that could easily offset any presumed benefits associated with mergers. The essence of any structural overview of a modern banking and financial system is the nature of the conduits through which the financial assets of the ultimate savers flow to the liabilities of the ultimate users of finance. These conduits involve alternative and competing modes of financial intermediation, or “contracting,” between counterparties in financial transactions both within and between national financial systems. Outside the home market, firms may adopt a narrower competitive profile, perhaps focusing on wholesale banking and securities activities, asset management and private banking, or perhaps a self-standing retail presence abroad. This presents shareholders with an amalgam of more or less distinct businesses that are linked together in a complex network that draws on a set of centralized financial, information, human, and organizational resources. Such a profile can be extraordinarily difficult to manage in a way that achieves an optimum use of invested capital. Excess retail production and distribution capacity in banking has been slimmed down in ways that usually release redundant labour and capital. This is a key objective of consolidation in financial services generally, as it is in any industry. If effective, surviving firms tend to be more efficient and innovative than those that do not survive. In some cases this process is retarded by restrictive regulation, by cartels, or by large-scale involvement of public sector financial institutions that operate under less rigorous financial discipline or are beneficiaries of public subsidies. Also at the retail level, commercial banking activity has been linked strategically to retail brokerage, retail insurance (especially life insurance), and retail asset management through mutual funds, retirement products, and private client relationships. At the same time, relatively small and focused firms have sometimes continued to prosper in each of the retail businesses, especially where they have been able to provide superior service or client proximity while taking advantage of outsourcing and strategic alliances where appropriate. Competitive market economics should be free to separate the winners and the losers. Significant departures from this logic need to be carefully watched and, if necessary, redressed by public policy. In wholesale financial services, similar links have emerged. Wholesale commercial banking activities such as syndicated lending and project financing have often been shifted toward a greater investment banking focus, whereas investment banking firms have placed growing emphasis on developing institutional asset management businesses in part to benefit from vertical integration and in part to gain some degree of stability in a notoriously volatile industry. Vigorous debates have raged about the need to lend in order to obtain valuable advisory business and whether specialized “monoline” investment banks will eventually be driven from the market by financial conglomerates with massive capital and risk-bearing ability. No consensus has been reached as yet and there is ample evidence that can be cited on both sides of the argument. This discussion has argued that on the whole, M&A activity in the financial services industry is driven by straightforward, underlying economic factors in the financial intermediation process dominated by a constant search for static and dynamic efficiency. If bigger is better, restructuring will produce larger financial services organizations. If broader is better, it will give rise to multifunctional firms and financial conglomerates. If not, then further restructuring activity will eventually lead to spin-offs and possibly break ups once it becomes clear that the composite value of a firm's individual businesses exceeds its market capitalization. Along the way, it is natural that mistakes are made and a certain herd mentality that exists in banking and financial services seems to cause multiple firms to get carried away strategically at the same time. Still, in the end, the economic fundamentals tend to win out. Proposal question: The proposal question is what are the effects of the merger of UK banks and what works, what fails and why. Literature review The empirical evidence for the existence of the market concentration-market power relationship is mixed. The effects of asymmetric information (also called the Akerlof effect) have been disentangled from studies to obtain a better understanding of market philosophy. Some influential papers have suggested a positive relationship between concentration and the degree of market power. For example an analysis of a cross-section of banking markets found, after controlling for various factors affecting price-setting behavior, that deposit rates are significantly lower in the most concentrated markets. Other work compares the time-series behavior of the deposit interest rate (and/or the loan rate) with the benchmark money market rate, which is not controlled by the banks. If banks have market power, they will, for example, quickly lower the deposit rate when the money market rate decreases, but the deposit rate will be sluggish when the money market rate increases. Conversely, in perfect competition one should expect quick reactivity in both cases. Evidence has been found of deposit rate rigidity and, thus, evidence of market power in the U.K. banking industry. Importantly, they find a higher level of rigidity in markets with higher HHIs. (HERFINDAHL-HIRSCHMAN INDEX --A measure of market concentration that's used primarily in merger cases.) However, some doubts have been cast on the market concentration-market power relationship. New findings suggests that the market concentration-market power relationship may not be monotonic. Such a relationship already holds at low levels of concentration, but in markets with middle levels of concentration the relationship vanishes, and it actually changes sign in highly concentrated markets (although this is a less robust result). In other words, at higher levels of concentration, an increase in concentration may imply less anticompetitive behavior. In another work focusing on the rigidity of deposit rates, Jackson (1997) presents additional evidence that the market concentration-market power relationship may not be monotonic. He finds that while it is true that at high levels of concentration price rigidity increases, this is also the case at low levels of concentration. This suggests a U-shaped relationship between market power and market concentration which is not consistent with the structure-conduct-performance hypothesis. Structural characteristics may vary widely for markets exhibiting similar Hill levels. In particular, the market share distribution may differ substantially. Firms' conduct may be very different depending on market share distribution. Rhoades shows that market share inequality and the number of firms in the market have an effect on banks' profitability that is independent of the HHI despite the fact that the HHI incorporates information on both market share variability and the number of firms. Finally, a lack of strong theoretical foundations and mixed empirical evidence motivate the search for alternative methodologies to investigate firms' competitive behavior Methodology: The methodology observed in this paper is the "new empirical industrial organization" which analyze firms' conduct directly, instead of relying on observation of the market structure. Following this approach, the relationship between theory and firms' conduct becomes unambiguous. For instance, as mentioned earlier, if banks are behaving as Cournot oligopolists, the market concentration-market power relationship would be theoretically grounded and the use of the HHI to infer firms' conduct would be appropriate. This alternative methodology allows us to test whether indeed banks behave as Cournot oligopolists. However, the methodology is flexible enough to allow us to test for behavior that could be consistent with alternative models of oligopoly theory. The following example illustrates the intuition. Suppose there is an exogenous increase in the demand for bank loans. In response, banks will take into account the cost they would incur in increasing the quantity of loans, the reactivity of demand itself to possible increases in the loan rate, and the expected reaction of the other banks in the market to their chosen course of action. In particular, the degree of interaction with the other banks in the market could differ substantially, depending on whether banks are in perfect competition with each other or enjoy some degree of market power. More precisely, the parameter of banks' interaction should be equal to 0 if the market is perfectly competitive, equal to 1 if it is monopolistic, and should take intermediate values between 0 and 1 if banks are neither perfectly competitive nor monopolistic but still exercise a positive degree of market power. Using appropriate econometric modeling techniques, one can estimate this parameter of interaction and, therefore, a quantifiable measure of market power. The advantage of this approach is that it is rigorously based on theory and does not require indirect (and perhaps ambiguous) inferences about market power through measures of market concentration. The major limitation of the approach is that it requires detailed information, mainly on cost and demand conditions at the firm level. Discussion Mergers and acquisitions in the banking sector are driven by the strategies of individual management teams who believe it is in their organization's best interests to reconfigure their businesses, hoping to achieve greater market share and profitability and therefore higher valuations of their firms. They believe that these gains will come from economies of scale, improved operating efficiencies, better risk control, the ability to take advantage of revenue synergies and other considerations, and are convinced they can overcome whatever economic and managerial disadvantages may arise. Sometimes they are right. Sometimes they are wrong, and net gains may turn out to be illusory or the integration process may be botched. In the end, the market will decide. And when the markets are subject to shocks, such as changes in economic fundamentals or technologies, they usually trigger a spate of M&A transactions that often seem to be amplified by herd-like behaviour among managements of financial firms. Public policy comes into the picture in several more or less distinct ways. The point is that mergers and acquisitions in the financial sector carry with them a substantial public interest element. Sometimes they are driven by measures taken in the public interest. Sometimes they themselves drive those measures. It is an unstable equilibrium that will surely persist as a key facet of the national and global financial environment in the years ahead. Applications to the banking industry Spiller and Favaro (1984) estimate the parameter of banks' interaction for the Uruguayan banking industry in a period characterized by a significant relaxation of entry regulations. They apply a refinement of the methodology proposed by Gollop and Roberts (1979) to see whether different groups of banks have different reactions to other groups' change in behavior. They reject Cournot conduct and find evidence of dominant firm-competitive fringe behavior, with a significant degree of oligopoly power, although this is substantially reduced after deregulation. Gelfand and Spiller (1987) extend the analysis of Uruguayan banks, treating the banks as multiproduct firms, the products being loans in the domestic currency and in U.K. pounds. They find evidence of noncompetitive behavior and, in particular, behavior consistent with mutual forbearance, whereby firms avoid changing behavior in one market fearing retaliation in another market, and with spoiling, whereby firms adopt predatory strategies. Applying the methodology to the Norwegian banking industry, Berg and Kim (1994) find that Cournot behavior is strongly rejected by the data and that instead banks behave as if they expect retaliation from their competitors in response to a change in their own behavior. Berg and Kim (1996) also investigate Norwegian banks as multiproduct firms, distinguishing between the retail and corporate banking markets. They find banks' degree of oligopoly power to be relatively high in the retail market and lower in the corporate market. Interestingly, the Herfindahl indicators for the two markets analyzed suggest opposite findings. Shaffer (1989), using aggregate data for the U.K. banking industry, finds no evidence of oligopoly power. Similarly, in a study of Canadian banking, Shaffer finds that despite structural and regulatory changes, Canadian banks operate in a market exhibiting perfect competition. In-Market and Cross-Market Transactions In-market transactions have been most intense in the commercial banking sector, notably retail banking. Extensive banking overcapacity in some countries has led to substantial consolidation that has often involved M&A activity. Excess retail banking capacity has been slimmed down in ways that usually release redundant labor and capital. In some cases this process has been retarded by large-scale involvement of public sector institutions and cooperatives that operate under less rigorous financial discipline. Most of the shrinkage in U. S. commercial banking, from almost 15,000 banks to about 8,000 banks, has been the product of M&A deals that included periods of high-volume activity by regional and super regional consolidators. In the process, the commercial banking industry has become far more efficient, yet without precluding the continued existence and prosperity of small community banks. In-market consolidation in investment banking had been a long-standing phenomenon—notably the accelerated consolidation triggered by deregulation in the United States and the United Kingdom. Finally, asset management has also seen substantial in-market restructuring as larger fund managers acquired smaller ones unable to exploit scale economies or lacking sufficient marketing reach. Another dimension of financial services consolidation is reflected in cross-market M&A transactions. At the retail level, commercial banking activity has been linked strategically to retail brokerage, retail insurance (especially life insurance), and retail asset management through mutual funds, retirement products, and private client relationships. Sometimes this product linkage has occurred selectively and sometimes by using multiple distribution channels coupled to aggressive cross-selling efforts. At the same time, relatively small and focused firms have sometimes continued to prosper in each of the retail businesses, especially where they have been able to provide superior service or client proximity while taking advantage of outsourcing and strategic alliances. In wholesale financial services, similar links have emerged. Wholesale commercial banking activities such as syndicated lending and project financing have often been shifted toward a greater investment banking focus, while investment banking firms have placed growing emphasis on developing institutional asset management businesses in part to benefit from vertical integration and in part to gain some degree of stability in a notoriously volatile industry. The result has been M&A activity on the part of commercial banks and universal banks acquiring investment banks, exploiting the U. K. regulatory liberalization that allowed them to do so. This activity paralleled to some extent the acquisition of brokers and jobbers as well as merchant banking firms in the United Kingdom, mostly by commercial and universal banks. Earlier, a number of insurance companies had likewise acquired investment banks. Most of these were later divested. Only Prudential Financial retains an in-house securities firm, Prudential Securities, which basically focuses on retail brokerage and even that business was partially sold to Wachovia Bank. Among the major banks there have been similar divestitures, for example Robertson Stephens by Fleet Financial in 2002. Outside the United Kingdom there were similar developments, including acquisition of Indosuez by Credit Agricole, Banque Paribas by Banque Nationale de Paris, Morgan Grenfell by Deutsche Bank, Hoare Govett by ABN AMRO, Barings by ING Groep, Wasserstein Perella by Dresdner Bank, and a number of others. Again, some were later divested as firms such as Barclays and National Westminster Bank exited key investment banking activities and sold these businesses to Crédit Suisse and Bankers Trust, respectively. The latter was subsequently taken over by Deutsche Bank. At the same time there has been substantial cross-market activity linking banking and insurance under the rubric of Allfinanz or bancassurance. Firms such as Citigroup, ING Groep, Allianz AG, Fortis Group, Lloyds TSB, and others offer both banking and insurance. In most cases these strategies involve acquisitions of insurance companies by commercial banking organizations or vice versa. The results have been decidedly mixed, ranging from considerable successes to unmitigated disasters. As always, the devil is in the details. Finally, each of the other three types of financial firms has aggressively expanded their presence in asset management, often through cross-market M&A deals. Market valuations of asset management companies have consequently been quite high in comparison with other types of firms in the financial services industry, and this has been reflected in prices paid in M&A transactions. Besides gaining access to distribution and fund management expertise, the underlying economics of this deal-flow presumably have to do with the realization of economies of scale and economies of scope, making possible both cost reductions and cross-selling of multiple types of funds, banking and/or insurance services, investment advice, high-quality research, and so on in a one-stop-shopping interface for investors. Financial services M&A transactions can be either inmarket or cross-market, in addition to being either domestic or crossborder. During the 1985–2002 period, most financial services M&A transactions were in-market, with firms acquiring or merging with similar firms, rather than cross-market. Until late 1999 the United Kingdom had in place significant barriers to cross-market M&A activity. These barriers certainly contributed to the fact that such a large proportion (85%) of the M&A activity was within each of the sectors and rather than between them. Nevertheless, in Europe, where such restrictions have not limited the process of financial restructuring, over 74% of the transactions by value were likewise within the individual financial services sectors. This suggests that the dynamics of financial services industry restructuring in the United Kingdom and Europe may have been quite similar, driven by the economics of consolidation within the industry's various functional domains. It is interesting that the relative volume of insurance deals was substantially higher in Europe than in the United Kingdom. Finally, the bulk of M&A transactions flow was domestic during the 1985–2002 period, that is, within national financial systems. This suggests that much of the volume concerned the consolidation of domestic banking systems, with M&A transactions being the principal vehicle for removing excess capacity and promoting domestic consolidation. The largest share of cross-border volume was in the insurance industry, suggesting that perhaps the underlying economics were somewhat different in that sector, with market-extension in the face of saturated domestic markets arguably representing an important motivation. Whereas line-of-business and geographic restrictions have characterized the United Kingdom for all but the last several years covered by the M&A data, fostering a more narrow geographic and line-of-business focus to financial sector restructuring than might have occurred otherwise, this was not the case in Europe. The EU Second Banking Directive and directives covering investment services and insurance all had in common the “single passport,” allowing financial firms to operate throughout the European Union (EU) in competition with local institutions. This did not mean a true level playing field, however, since the EU lacked a coherent set of takeover rules during this period and continued to be characterized by strong nationalism and the perceived need for “national champions” in the financial sector, particularly banking. Cross-border restructuring in the United Kingdom was probably the most liberal, with most securities firms and a number of banks, insurance companies, and asset managers taken over by foreign players. The largest deal was the acquisition of Midland Bank by HSBC. Still, there were also a number of cross-border deals in France, Germany, Italy, Spain, Portugal, and the Nordic and Benelux countries. Example: An example of a merger between two UK banks is the merger of the Halifax and the Bank of Scotland which took place in 2001. The deal was worth twenty eight billion pounds and created Britain’s fifth largest bank. The new institution is called HBOS and is based in Edinburgh. Some 2000 jobs were lost in the process. 8.163.650.646.4 After the merger, HBOS earnings per share rose from 46.4 pence in 2001 to 78.1 pence in 2004 Results The evidence suggests that the net gains from M&A transactions come either on the cost and efficiency side or the revenue side of the combined businesses. The key lessons from the evidence, on the cost side, appear to be the following. For entire financial firms there appear to be few economies of scale (unit cost reductions associated with larger size, all else remaining the same) to be harvested in the banking, insurance, and securities industries beyond relatively small firm size. Moreover, cost differences attributable to economies of scale tend to be relatively small compared to total costs and compared to cost differences between the most and least efficient firms in these sectors. Nor is there much evidence of diseconomies of scale beyond optimum-size firms. So cost economies of scale are not likely to be an appropriate motivation for M&A deals, especially large ones, nor are the possibility of diseconomies of scale likely to represent a compelling argument against them. However, since financial firms usually consist of an amalgam of scale sensitive and non-scale-sensitive activities, M&A transactions can add significant value if product-level scale economies are aggressively exploited. Obvious candidates include various kinds of mass-market consumer financial services, securities custody, trade financing, and the like. Working against possible scale and efficiency gains in mergers and acquisitions are costs associated with complexity. Larger firms are harder to manage than smaller ones. It is not easy to instill compelling cost discipline, teamwork and a common culture in a firm with several hundred thousand people scattered across hundreds of locations, possibly globally. While this may be possible at the world's largest employer, Wal-Mart, banking and financial services are another matter altogether. It means a high degree of complexity, and complexity usually means increased costs. Also in the realm of costs are conflicts of interest between the firm and its clients, as well as between clients. Regardless of size, a greater range of products, clients, and locations spell greater potential for conflicts of interest. Exploitation of these conflicts must be prevented by means of conduct guidelines and effective “Chinese walls” that limit some of the hoped-for synergies. But the costs of dealing with conflicts of interest after they occur can be horrendous, as banks' involvement in corporate financial scandals has demonstrated. Revenues may collapse as the firm's reputation takes a serious hit. Or costs may balloon as the firm scrambles to rescue its good name or deals with class-action litigation. Either way, preventing and managing conflicts of interest can and do show up on both the cost and revenue sides of the ledger in scoping out the possible effects of an M&A deal. In short, on the cost side, the managerial lessons are don't expect too much from economies of scale on a firm wide basis, but work to exploit them in scale-sensitive businesses while aggressively pursuing operating efficiencies by shedding redundant resources as quickly as possible for an “early harvest” in the value of the transaction to shareholders. At the same time, create incentive-compatible managerial structures that help immunize the firm from the costs of complexity and exploitation of conflicts of interest, especially those creating potential franchise risks for the business. Conclusion This paper has presented an overview of the methodologies used in competitive analysis of the banking industry. Given the ongoing process of consolidation in the U.K. banking industry, properly identifying the conditions for the exercise of banks' market power is highly relevant for policy analysis. The empirical evidence on the existence of the market concentration-market power relationship is rather mixed, in light of several recent works that cast doubt on the robustness of such a relationship. An alternative methodology for the identification of parameters of firms' conduct and the degree of market power, which does not rely on indirect inferences of market structure analysis, requires an econometric estimation of market demand and supply conditions. The testable implications associated with this approach allow us to unambiguously identify firms' conduct. The results from an empirical application of this methodology to the Italian banking industry provide evidence that contradicts the inferences of the structure-conduct-performance approach. Adopting this alternative methodology to identify the parameter of banks' interaction brings a higher rigor to the antitrust analysis, implicit in the econometric exercise required to extract information from industry data. This is, however, also its principal shortcoming, in terms of the need for more detailed data and the greater difficulty associated with the implementation and interpretation of the econometric work. Conversely, the main advantage of the current approach to competitive analysis is that HHI indicators are relatively easy to compute and allow the regulators to formulate objective statements and deliver opinions that are less subject to arbitrary judgments. Nonetheless, it is important to recognize the potential shortcomings of the current approach and to test for accountability when developments in economic research provide the appropriate tools. For example, the alternative methodology presented in this paper could be applied to markets in which mergers have been approved to analyze banks' conduct before and after the change in market structure." In addition to an "after the fact" analysis, the methodology could be used routinely to overview market conditions and to provide ex ante information that could be used by regulators when a merger application is filed, perhaps to resolve potential ambiguities associated with mere observation of market structure. In this way, the methodology could be adopted to complement the current procedure for antitrust analysis. >>>>> Paper ends >>>>>> Reference: 1)Angelini, P., and N, Cetorelli, 1998, "Assessing competition in the Italian banking industry," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, mimeo. 2)Berg, S. A., and M. Kim, 1996, "Banks as multioutput oligopolies: An empirical evaluation of the retail and corporate banking markets," in Proceedings Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, pp. 183-201. 3)Berger, A., and T. Hannan, 1989. "The price-concentration relationship in banking," Review of Economies and Statistics, Vol. 71, May, pp. 291-299. 4)Gelfand, M., and Spiller, P., 1987, "Entry barriers and multiproduct oligopolies," International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 5, March, pp. 101-113. 5)Gollop, F., and M. Roberts, 1979, "Firm interdependence in oligopolistic markets," Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 10, August, pp. 310-331. 6)Hannan, T., and A. Berger, 1991, "The rigidity of prices: Evidence from the banking industry," American Economic Review, Vol. 81. No. 4, pp. 938-945. 7)Jackson, W., III, 1997, "Market structure and the speed of adjustment: Evidence of non-monotonicity," Review of Industrial Organization, Vol. 12, February, pp. 37-57 Top of Form     8)Bank of England|Publications|News|1998|Merger of CGO, CMO and CREST 18.09.98 News Release, Merger of CGO, CMO and CREST, 17 September 1998 ...   9)Bank of England|Publications|Speeches|By Date|2001|Speech by David Clementi, Deputy Governor Speech by David Clementi, Deputy Governor at a Banca d'Italia Conference - International Banking and Financial Systems: Evolution and Stability - in Rome on 9 March 2001 ...   10)Bank of England|Publications|News|1999|Guidance on Share Issuing Good Practice 28.10.99 News Release, Guidance on Share Issuing Good Practice, 28 October 1999 ...   11)Bank of England|Publications|News|1997|Reforms in the London Markets 18.11.97 Reforms in the London Markets - Speech by Ian Plenderleith on 18 November ...   12)Bank of England|Publications|News|1998 News Release, ...   13)Bank of England|Publications|News|1997|Foreign Exchange Settlement Risk 30.09.97 Foreign Exchange Settlement Risk, 30 September 1997 ...   14)Bank of England|Publications|Main Publications|Practical Issues Arising From The Euro|June 2001 Issue Practical Issues Arising From The Euro, June 2001 Issue. ...   15)Bank of England|Publications|Other Publications|City Handbook|Alphabetical Listing T The City Handbook, Alphabetical Listing T ...   16)Bank of England|Publications|News|2001|Chairman and Deputy Chairman of the Appeal Committee of the Takeover Panel News Release:Chairman and Deputy Chairman of the Appeal Committee of the Takeover Panel ...   19)http://www.dallasfed.org/banking/fis/index.html 17)Economic Integration and Banking Mergers Strategies (José García Solanes and Diego Peñarrubia) 18)http://www.wgreenblatt.com/investmentbanking_maacq.htm  20)http://www.compcom.co.za/thelaw/thelaw_glossary. London School of Economics 21) PREST Prest; Alan Richmond 22) IONIAN BANK/3/21 Court of Directors minutes no. 26 23) COLL MISC 0004 Jones Lloyd and Company 24) COLL MISC 0364 Sayers; Richard Sidney 25) COLL MISC 0448 Palgrave; Sir; Robert Harry Inglis 26) The Banking Code, UK – British Banking Association 27) Review of Banking Services in the UK – HM Treasury 28) Fiscal Policy – HM Treasury 29) Mergers and acquisitions - Bordering on success - John Rushton, PA Consulting Group 30)Banking on Acquisitions – Steve Hannaford, Oligopoly Watch 31) Retail banking Mergers and Acquisitions- Capgemini 32) The Future of the UK Banking Sector – Kay Reynolds 33) Proposed merger of Halifax Bank and Bank of Scotland – OFT, UK 34) www.scotbanks.org.uk/history.htm 35) www.acquisitions-monthly.com/ 36) Corporate Financing Focus –Mergers and Acquisitions – Gordon Platt 37) Bank Mergers and the Public Interest – Public Interest Advocacy Center 38) Merge or die – Streeter, Cocheo 39) www.hbosplc.com 40) The FDI Race in European Banking - Philip Molyneux 41) What determines banks’ market power ? Akerlof vs Henfindahl – Moshe Kim, Eirik Gaard Kristiansen, Bert Vale 42) Decomposing Credit Spreads – Rohan Churm and Nikolaus Paringintzglou 43) Competetivesness, inflation and monetary policy – Hashmet Khan and Richhild Moessner 44) Longterm Intrest Rates, Credit and Consumption – Roy Cromb, Emilio Fernandez-Corugedo 45) Core Inflation, A critical guide – Alan Mankikar and Jo Paisley 46) Anticipation of Monetary Policy in UK - Peter Lidholdt and Anne Vila Wetherhilt 47) Evolving Post World War 2 UK Economic Performance – Luca Benati 48) Financial Interlinkages in the UK in the Interbank Market and the Risk of Contagion – Simon Wells 49) On the Resolution of Banking Crises – Theorey and Evidence - Glen Hoggarth, Jack Reidhill and Peter Sinclair 50) Capital Flows to Emerging Markets – Adrian Penalver 51) Corportate Capital Structures in the UK, Determinants and Adjustments – Philip Bunn and Gary Young 52) Estimating Real Interest rates for the UK – Jens Larsen, Ben May and James Talbot Note for the client from the writer 1 - What HHI? You should mention the abbreviation of the word. Expansion and definition included 2 - The literature review based on some research which are old and not enoughl as well not from the UK new research. This section reworked with some new input 3 - The references are only 17 and I asked for minimum 30.from the UK. References increased to 52. This includes UK as well as overseas authors due to the nature of the text Also, please make sure that these points are mentioned in the proposal: 1 - the proposal question is: M&A in the UK banking:what works? what fails? and why? Proposal question highlighted with this font colour 2 - the hypotheses and the purpose of the study as they are main point in the proposal dissertation. Hypothesis and purpose of study highlighted with this font colour 3 - what is the methodolody that has been used? Methodology highlighted with this font colour 4 - the literature review should be based on a UK reaserch and references (minimum 30 reference) and there should cover some examples from the UK banking industry. UK references and one example of the merger of Halifax bank and bank of Scotland have been included 5 - the writer mentioned a big example about the italian banking whereas should be from the uk banking which the professor did not find it relevant. The Italian banking example has been removed and an English bank merger included finally the word count is maximum for 5000 and the proposal is for 5238. Word count for the article excluding refrences is 4464 I trust this reworked article is to your satisfaction. Cheers ! Bottom of Form . Read More
Cite this document
  • APA
  • MLA
  • CHICAGO
(Mergers and Acquisitions in UK Banking Term Paper, n.d.)
Mergers and Acquisitions in UK Banking Term Paper. https://studentshare.org/finance-accounting/2041692-revise-mergers-and-aquisitions-in-the-uk-banking
(Mergers and Acquisitions in UK Banking Term Paper)
Mergers and Acquisitions in UK Banking Term Paper. https://studentshare.org/finance-accounting/2041692-revise-mergers-and-aquisitions-in-the-uk-banking.
“Mergers and Acquisitions in UK Banking Term Paper”. https://studentshare.org/finance-accounting/2041692-revise-mergers-and-aquisitions-in-the-uk-banking.
  • Cited: 0 times

CHECK THESE SAMPLES OF Mergers and Acquisitions in the UK Banking

Laws and Forms of Business Ownership

They should also have a good knowledge of its legal status, debts and obligations depending on the nature and form of the business and how it has been registered in the uk (Federation of Small Business Website, 2012, 1) Forms of Business Ownership While the form of business ownership to be adopted depends both on the number of owners and the funds, skills or both that they are willing to contribute and invest in the business, this can often be a very tricky though pertinent question requiring considerable thought....
6 Pages (1500 words) Essay

Retail Marketing

The uk supermarket segment has recently embraced various store formats.... The researcher states that the retailer converts the large amounts into smaller amounts or quantities and then sells them to consumers at a profit.... Retailing is usually done either in fixed locations such as markets or stores, by delivery, or door-to-door....
8 Pages (2000 words) Essay

Bank of America

Bank of America Table of Contents Perspective of the Board of Bank of America 3 Perspective of the shareholders of Bank of America 4 Perspective of the shareholders of MBNA 5 Perspective of the hedge fund 5 Perspective of the US Federal Trade Commission 6 References 8 Perspective of the Board of Bank of America The acquisition of MBNA by the Bank of America reflects the strategic issues in the credit card business for the Board of Bank of America....
5 Pages (1250 words) Assignment

Diversified Bank Capital One

Functioning exclusively in the banking business, the company is at a high leveraged state.... The retail banking industry is highly attractive which lures new entrants into this industry.... The economic condition has revived in the developing countries but the developed countries like uk and US will take more time to come out of this economic shock.... In America, the company has a strong brand image and it is one of the top 10 banks… In the past, the company has under gone several acquisitions; as for example in 2005, Capital One acquired Hibernia National Bank and entered the retail business....
6 Pages (1500 words) Essay

The Economic Growth of a Country

This essay "Corporate Finance" seeks to enquire how far the quote “In today's economic climate, any company that hasn't borrowed as much as it can is crazy" is relevant within the context of corporate finance principles.... hellip; it becomes clear that a company need not borrow as much as it can unless it is really warranted....
6 Pages (1500 words) Essay

Business Combinations & Segment Reporting - Restaurant Brands

will acquire the whole of the assets of Weenie Ltd.... through the issue of Whopper Ltd.... Shares to the total value of these assets.... The assets (of Weenie Ltd.... under consideration have the following value:- The assets, for the purposes of the… will therefore be taken to be $303,000....
9 Pages (2250 words) Assignment
sponsored ads
We use cookies to create the best experience for you. Keep on browsing if you are OK with that, or find out how to manage cookies.
Contact Us